Last week, 35 public school teachers and administrators indicted for allegedly cheating to raise test scores in an Atlanta school district began turning themselves in to authorities. They may be the tip of the iceberg; a state investigation implicates 178 educators in the scandal.
Lynn Stout is a professor of business and corporate law at Cornell Law School and the author of "Cultivating Conscience: How Good Laws Make Good People."Were these teachers and principals all "bad apples," intrinsically unethical individuals who somehow ended up in the same school district? Not likely. They were ordinary people who allegedly did unethical and dishonest things to achieve the student performance targets needed to keep their jobs and earn their bonuses. The Atlanta cheating scandal illustrates the dangers of the modern infatuation with incentives and what's called "pay for performance."
Atlanta Public Schools defendant Sandra Ward, right, turns herself in at the Fulton County Jail accompanied by her attorney
Lawmakers often view incentives as the answer to almost every policy problem. Stock returns lagging? Change the tax code — as Congress did in 1993 — to require executive pay to be linked to "objective metrics." Medicare costs spiraling upward? Launch a pilot program — as the Department of Health and Human Services has — basing physician payments on measured outcomes. Children failing to learn their ABCs? Tie teacher pay — as Atlanta's school district did — to student test scores.
What happened in Atlanta is only the latest instance in which performance incentives tempted employees into opportunistic, even illegal behavior. During the 2008 credit crisis, performance-based pay lured mortgage brokers into approving unqualified borrowers and financial executives into making risky derivatives bets. Incentive pay played a leading role in the Enron and WorldCom frauds. It was implicated in the 1980s savings and loan crisis.
These cases show the underbelly of pay for performance. Explicit incentives work for simple tasks where an employee controls the outcome and where product quality is easily assessed — for example, offering employees of a moving company $20 for every sofa they move in an hour without damage. It's pretty clear whether the sofas got moved, and whether they got damaged.
But what about complex, hard-to-monitor tasks where the desired outcome is difficult to measure and subject to influences outside the employee's control — such as educating a child or restoring a patient to health? It is almost impossible to design objective performance metrics that can't be met through illegal or undesirable behavior. In the case of education, it could be falsifying student test scores; in the case of healthcare, it could be controlling blood pressure through medications that make patients feel sick instead of persuading patients to exercise. And when you create a system that inadvertently incentivizes illegal or undesirable behavior, you get more of it.
Policymakers and reformers assume the solution is "getting the incentives right." They believe incentives might help and can't possibly hurt. But as the Atlanta scandal shows, and as social science has proved, incentives can hurt. Pay for performance can create workplaces that suppress ethics and conscience. Instead of more productive employees, you get more opportunistic, unethical and criminal employees. Incentive plans are like dynamite — useful but also dangerous. These plans should be handled only by experts, with great care and in small amounts.
What is the alternative to pay for performance? It's worth remembering that before free-market ideology and the dogma of incentives took root, employers often compensated employees — including teachers, doctors and business executives — with flat salaries and modest bonuses adjusted annually according to the employer's opinion of whether the employee had done well. The system relied on subjective, after-the-fact rewards more than objective, predetermined incentives. That required a fair amount of trust and a sense of mutual obligation. Employers had to trust employees to work to earn their predetermined salaries rather than loafing. (Bad employees can be fired, but this solution costs the employer too.) Employees had to trust that if they stuck around and did a great job, their employers would recognize and reward them.
Standard economic theory predicts that systems based on mutual trust and respect between employer and employee shouldn't work. But innumerable behavioral studies prove trust is a real phenomenon, and history shows it can indeed motivate employees. For example, before Congress changed the tax code in 1993 to tie executive pay to objective performance metrics, boards paid CEOs far less. Yet investors enjoyed higher stock market returns than today.
This doesn't mean pay for performance is always bad. When the task is simple and it's easy to spot employee misconduct — remember those sofa movers — incentive plans can get better results than a flat salary. Crude incentive plans that look only at a few simple performance measures and that are driven by the demands of elected politicians are especially dangerous.
We should let employers and supervisors on the front lines of the workplace — not politicians, bureaucrats or would-be reformers — decide how best to motivate employees. They might decide they need more trust, and fewer incentives.
1 comment:
Incentive works if you have legitimate control of the product's production. If I were making stool legs on a lathe, I could control the speed of spin, tools for making the cut, quality of wood used, a detailed design print and have a specific quota to produce.
For the devil of me, I have no idea why educated people think they can apply the industrial model I have just described to teaching. You are expecting some sort of standardized product (All students competent in all areas) yet your base resource, tools and production plans, schedules and quotas are completely different for each work station. If presented with these inconsistent work conditions in making stool legs, we would no doubt end up with a spectrum of quality and even products which would certainly be less than standard. Why in the world do we think we would get anything different when dealing with someting as complex as teaching students. Just because we present folks with a common production blue print and quota doesn't mean we are going to get a standardized product when the resouce, tools and craftmans' skills are different at each work station. Equally, we can't just blame the craftsman everytime when are provideing him or her with dull and inprecise tools and expect knotty pine wood and white poplar or oak to result in the same quality of product.
Post a Comment